|
Policy Contribution
Contribution to key objectives and alleviation of key problems for Manchester
Metrolink, Sheffield Supertram and other systems is summarised below,
with more detailed discussion of each following.
Summary of different systems’ contribution to key objectives
| = Weakest
possible positive contribution, | | = strongest
possible positive contribution |
| = Weakest
possible negative contribution | | = strongest
possible negative contribution |
| =
No contribution |
Overall summary of different systems’ contribution to alleviation
of key problems
Problem |
Manchester Metrolink |
Sheffield Supertram |
Other systems |
Congestion-related delay |
|
|
|
Congestion-related unreliability |
|
|
|
Community severance |
|
|
|
Visual intrusion |
- |
- |
- |
Lack of amenity |
|
|
|
Global warming |
|
|
|
Local air pollution |
|
|
|
Noise |
|
|
|
Reduction of green space |
|
|
|
Damage to environmentally sensitive sites |
- |
- |
- |
Poor accessibility for those without a car and
those with mobility impairments |
|
|
|
Disproportionate disadvantaging of particular
social or geographic groups |
|
|
|
Number, severity and risk of accidents |
|
|
|
Suppression of the potential for economic activity
in the area |
|
|
|
Appropriate contexts
The table below provides some indication of the suitability of light
rail transit for different area types.
Appropriate area-types |
Area type |
Suitability |
City centre |
|
Dense inner suburb |
|
Medium density outer suburb |
|
Less dense outer suburb |
|
District centre |
|
Corridor |
|
Small town |
|
Tourist town |
|
Adverse side-effects of light rail
Light rail does not have many direct adverse effects, although noise,
visual intrusion and increasing social inequality (because of serving
high-income areas) have been indicated as examples. The first two tend
to be concerns prior to opening rather than real concerns during operation
as experience shows such systems are soon accepted as part of the urban
fabric. The social inequity problem largely relates to the use of resources,
as happened in Los Angeles where operating losses on the light rail system
had to be covered out of a public transport budget which meant diverting
resources away from low income bus users. This touches on the main adverse
effect of light rail schemes which is their huge cost. The capital cost
has to be paid out of public funds, and can be very high. Spending public
funds in this way means that funding is either diverted away from other
public goods and services or from private expenditure because taxes are
higher than they otherwise would be (in countries such as Britain the
higher taxes would not be explicitly linked to the new light rail system,
but in the US, local citizens can vote to increase the scheme is essentially
a political decision, which is not always rational (Edwards and Mackett,
1996, Richmond, 2001). Even if the decision to build a new light rail
system is not rational there is a clear advantage in making it as successful
as possible, building upon experience from elsewhere as far as possible
(Mackett and Edwards, 1996). This is the rationale underlying the work
by Babalik (2000) and Mackett and Babalik (2001a,b).
|