Evidence on performance Parking Policy in Bern, Switzerland Parking Policy in Helsinki, Finland Parking Policy in Bern, Switzerland Context
Parking policy measures in Bern are summarised in “Parking Policy
Measures in the Urban Area of Bern” Parking Policy Measures in the Urban Area of Bern
*Blue Zones are located in residential areas. On weekdays parking is
limited to 60 minutes between 8am and 6pm. Three hour parking is permitted
in the interpeak period. In areas with a lot of leisure traffic, restrictions
can be extended to weekends. Residents (including businesses within the
Blue Zones can purchase a parking permit at a cost of 240 francs per month.
Visitors and other users can purchase daily parking permits. New local
legislation was required to enact Blue Zones, and as with other parking
measures, was subject to initial opposition and appeal from the Automobile
Club and some residents, who claimed that the system contradicted federal
law. The system was introduced in 1999, including the removal of 10% of
public parking spaces. Parking charges were to be increased from two Swiss francs in the central business district to four and from one franc to two in outer districts, plus the introduction of a one franc charge for park and ride spaces. However, there was significant opposition from the business community. As a compromise, only the charges in residential areas were increased; one day permits rose from 8 francs to 15 and new four hour permit was introduced fro 8 francs. Charges also became applicable 24 hours per day. External costs are not incorporated into the charges, as the necessary increases would be unacceptable in the current climate. It should also be noted that as the increase to four francs for city centre spaces was blocked, the local authority charge remains lower than that for privately operated car parks. There was also objection to the reduction in number of public parking spaces. The “Action Plan on Air Pollution” of 1992 promoted this, but the political will and legal basis was missing. A compromise was reached in 1997, resulting in a plan to move 154 ground level spaces from the old part of the city underground, to achieve a pedestrian friendly environment. However, objections were raised against enlarging existing subterranean car parks, resulting in no progress. Objections against limitations on duration of stay are not reported. thus, public spaces in the centre of Bern are subject to severe restrictions to deter car commuters and provide for visitors. Maximum duration restrictions vary between 15 and 60 minutes depending on charges and centrality. Many central spaces are free, but restricted to 30 or 60 minutes. It should also be noted that the introduction of a traffic management system within the city also included a parking guidance system. The first area-wide parking guidance system in Switzerland was introduced by the operators of private car parks in Bern in 1997. The system was funded by car users through a 0.10 franc per hour increase in charges. One year on, more customers were using car parks, including park and ride facilities on the outskirts, and revenues were higher than expected. The rest of the traffic management system has been blocked due to opposition on cost grounds, although discussions are on going. More restrictive controls were introduced for visitor parking around the exhibition centres and sports stadium, as the free public transport (for those with tickets) was not enough to dissuade drivers due to the plentiful free parking spaces. Consequently, fees of 5 francs per half day were introduced. Additionally, legislation was introduced to allow the introduction of White Zones with time limits applicable 24h hours a day, seven days a week. In these areas around the exhibition centres and stadium, parking is limited to 60 minutes unless special allowance has been obtained. As with the Blue Zones, residents’ permits can be purchased. A reservation system is also being investigated, such that only those with a pre-paid parking ticket may access spaces. On the outskirts of Bern, park and ride has become more important as parking restrictions in the centre and residential areas have increased. Park and ride facilities are operated privately (by a community or public transport operator for example) with financial support from the local authority. Support is dependent upon:
Parking spaces on local authority premises are also subject to regulations:
Private non-residential parking is also subject to regulations, but there is also substantial opposition. In some cases, this is from a canton disputing Federal Court decisions, not from private companies. The Federal Court ruled that the Canton of Bern must collect parking fees from the customers of new and existing shopping centres, however, this obligation has been dropped by the Canton. The handbook on “Implementation of Parking Policy Measures” was introduced to persuade organisations of the need for voluntary parking controls and explain how they should be planned, introduced and managed. Whilst shopping centres suffering from the poor image created by significant amounts of search traffic may introduce charges (somewhat unwillingly) the lack of compulsory measures for shopping centres is often used to argue against parking charges on public spaces in the centre of Bern. Indeed, opposition from companies has been less, due to the high opportunity cost they pay for their parking spaces, which is not traditionally passed on to employees. Fritz Studer AG only provide a parking space for employees living outside a certain area (i.e. beyond the reach of public transport), and even then a fee is charged. The more central the car park, the higher the charge. Revenues are used to maintain the car park and promote public transport use amongst employees. Planning regulations are also used to limit PNR around new developments, with the number of spaces more limited where the destination is well served by public transport. These measures are similar to the company travel plans introduced elsewhere. Impacts on demand and supply The Blue Zones have been the most successful element of the parking policy:
Parking fees applicable to public car parks and spaces around stadium
used for large events have been less successful: It was not possible in 2001 to assess other parking measures due to lack of implementation. Environmental Impacts Perception of Change in Air Pollution and Noise in Residential Areas
with Blue Zones (European Commission, 2001a) Economic Impacts Policy contribution
Parking Policy in Helsinki, Finland The case study reported here is taken from “Parking Policy Measures and their Effects on Mobility and the Economy. Case Studies - Finland” prepared for the COST (European Co-operation in the Field of Scientific and Technical Research) project Parking Policy Measures and their Effects on Mobility and the Economy, number 342. The report was produced in 2001. ContextHelsinki is a coastal metropolis and is the fastest growing in the EU. The city centre is sited on a peninsula 12Km2. The total population of the metropolitan area is 955,500, 65,000 of whom live in the city centre. There are 480,000 workplaces within the metropolis, 100,000 of which are in the centre. As in other developed cities, car use grew at the expense of other modes through out the 1970’s and 1980’s, although car ownership decreased in the early 1990’s as a result of economic depression. In 2001, car ownership stood at 360 per 1,000 inhabitants, with 605 of households owning at least one vehicle. Whilst modal split over the Helsinki metropolitan area indicates less car dependence than is apparent in many cities, the limited land access to the peninsula (9 streets) results in familiar problems resulting from car use. In view of this and the rapid growth, increasing the modal share of public transport is seen as essential. Modal split of total trips in Helsinki
(European Commission, 2001b) Modal split of total trips in Helsinki downtown
(European Commission, 2001b) As in Bern, parking policy aims to ensure that using public transport is more attractive than driving into the city. Public transport in Helsinki consists of bus, tram, three rail lines for commuter trains and one metro line. Over half of all public transport trips are by bus. In 2001 69% of motorised trips into the city centre in the morning rush hour trips were by public transport. Over the whole day, the share is 62%. The aim is to increase the morning peak share to 70% in the short term, and 75% in the long term (short and long term are not defined). Nevertheless, 260,000 vehicles cross the city centre border each day. Parking policy is designed to meet all non-commuter related demand for parking spaces within the inner city and suburban regions. Long-term parking in the city centre is discouraged. In the inner city area there are approximately 93,200 parking places, 36,500 of these are in the city centre and 4,000 of those are subject to a charge. Of the spaces in the city centre, 45% are on street (including residential parking), 11% are in parking facilities and 44% are private. It is notable that most parking facilities are located near to the main rail station in the heart of the city. The parking policy consists of the following measures:
The charges introduced for on-street parking vary according to centrality. In the central business district the charge is €2 per hour, areas surrounding the peninsula are €1 per hour, and the remainder of the inner city area is €0.5 per hour. Charges apply from 08:00 to 17:00 on weekdays and 09:00 to 15:00 on Saturdays in the central business district. In the central business district parking duration is restricted to one or two hours. If there is a restriction in other zones it is four hours. The highest charge for off-street parking facilities (mostly underground) is €2 per hour, and there are usually empty spaces available at all times of day and year. However, there are special rates for long-term and regular parking. Additionally, customers of near by shops may get price reductions or free parking if they spend enough on purchases. Whilst this charging regime is not particularly unique, the means of payment are novel. On-street parking can be paid for through conventional metering, pre-paid scratch card tickets to be displayed in the windscreen, or an in-car electronic meter with reloadable smart card. Use of this later means of payment allows holders to park anywhere within their designated zone, only pay the actual time they are parked and receive a 20% reduction in parking charges, although there is a €90 fixed charge for the meter and smart card. Approximately 25,000 in-car meters are in use. A pilot project to collect parking fees by mobile phone is also underway. A residents parking scheme has been in operation in Helsinki since 1983. A zone-specific residential licence is displayed in vehicles, allowing drivers to ignore time restrictions and charges (applicable to everybody else) within their designated zone. Licences are granted for a year at a time, but each individual may hold a licence for two vehicles. Since 1992, local businesses have been able to hold licences as well, and have parking priority. Firms can hold three permits per office. There are seven residential zones, with 15,200 spaces for 20,000 residential permit holders and 1,500 business permits. Residents pay €25.51 per annum, whilst businesses pay €252.10. Change in occupancy rates over time is reported for the period 10:00 to 14:00 in “Residential Parking Occupancy”
(European Commission, 2001b) The notable drop between 1994 and 1995 and consequent rise in occupancy rates is unlikely to be a result of the parking policy given that it pre-dated the surveys reported. It is possible that the pattern is a consequence of fewer shoppers using spaces due to the recession. Regardless the occupancy rates for other time periods throughout the day in 2000 suggest that demand is not exceeding supply at any point in the day. Inner Zone Occupancy Rates – Spring 2000
(European Commission, 2001b) Illegal parking is a problem in Helsinki. Almost 10% of on street and other public parking in the city centre is illegally parked. Unfortunately, the €35 fine is low compared to the cost of long-stay parking, but raising the fine requires legislation. (In time restricted free spaces a parking disc must be used). Revenue from parking meter and ticket sales, plus parking fines was €12.83 million. Impacts on Demand and SupplyImpacts reported here are based on stated preference modelling, which included a 30% increase in the parking charges. This increase resulted in modal shift representing an 8 to 10% reduction in the share of trips made by car. The change is greatest for trips between the home and workplace. Unsurprisingly, the greater the increase in parking charges, the greater the modal shift. Doubling the increase in charges approximately doubles the modal shift. It was also established that if parking costs and public transport fares were equal [i.e. parking charges were increased] for equivalent journeys, then the share of car trips would decrease by 8%. The change is quite small as the resulting parking charge would be €2.60 per day, which is small for the stated preference survey respondents, especially if the employer covers the cost. If public transport fares were reduced by 30%, then the modal share of the car would only decrease by 2%, suggesting that cheaper public transport does not induce significant modal shift and that parking charges are more effective. If the public transport fares were altered to equal the fuel cost of the equivalent journey by car, then there would be a 2% shift from car to public transport. Whilst these models suggest that small changes in parking charges do reduce car use, the effectives are not substantial. It was concluded that regulating the location of parking facilities would be more effective, as drivers do not like to walk. However, lack of control over existing private non-residential and off-street residential parking makes this option difficult. A walking distance of 400 metres between parking space and destination would result in a 9% decrease in the car share. If the walk distance were the same as that for the public transport alternative (based on routes that do not include transfers as people avoid this eventuality), then car share would decrease by 13%. Other Impacts Contribution to Objectives
Gaps and Weaknesses Whilst there is evidence on the effect of car parking controls, the body of evidence is not large. Additionally, the evidence on specific controls is not always seperated out – a wholistic approach to multiple controls is often taken. With regard to the Bern and Helsinki examples cited here; the controls appear to be under performing. In Bern parking charges form part of the controls package and they do not appear to be high enough. In Helsinki the supply of parking appears to be too great.
|