![]() |
![]() |
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() |
|
![]() |
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() |
![]() The range of transport policy instruments The detailed list of instruments Bases for assessing performance Sources of evidence Summary assessment Priorities and preferences Types of integration Potential Benefits from Integration The range of transport policy instruments These instruments can be categorised in several ways. The approach which
has been adopted in Konsult has been to group them under the following
six headings:
The detailed list of instruments
Attitudinal and behavioural measures These are measures which aim to change users' understanding of transport problems, or provide alternatives outside the transport sector, and hence induce changes in travel patterns. The principal ones are:
Infrastructure measures The measures listed under this heading involve additions or enhancements to the existing transport infrastructure. The main ones are: Measures to influence car use
Measures to influence public transport use
Provision for cyclists and pedestrians
Provision for freight
Management measures The measures listed under this heading involve changing the way in which the existing transport infrastructure is used. They involve a wide range of approaches, including increases and reductions in road capacity, reallocations of that capacity, and changes in the operation of public transport. They include: Measures to influence car use
Measures to influence public transport use
Provision for cyclists and pedestrians
Provision for freight
Information provision The measures listed under this heading involve improvements in the information available to transport users and operators. Some are traditional fixed information systems, others draw on real time applications of information technology. They include: Measures to influence car use
Measures to influence public transport use
Provisions for cyclists and pedestrians
Provision for freight
Pricing measures Measures to influence car use
Measures to influence public transport use
All of the above policy instruments will affect the performance of the
transport system in one or more of three ways:
Changes in demand
Some of these changes may be made immediately, while others may take longer, particularly if other activities have to be adjusted. For example, a change in destination for shopping journeys can be immediate, while one for work will depend on being able to change job. In addition there are two further responses which are almost certainly longer term ones:
In Level 2 the assessment considers in turn each of these types of potential change, and assesses for each whether they are likely to be short, medium and/or long term, and how strong the response is likely to be on a 0-3 scale. Similarly the case study results present evidence on this basis. The scale of response will depend very much on the circumstances. Those who are directly exposed to a change are likely to respond more strongly than those for whom information on the change is indirect. Thus car users are less likely than bus users to respond to a reduction in bus fares, while the reverse is true for fuel prices. Those for whom the journey, by the current means, is particularly important may well be more reluctant to change, unless the alternative offers a considerable improvement. Those who have few or no alternatives are obviously less likely to change. Longer term changes, and those with longer term implications, are likely to be dependent on perceptions of the consistency and continuity of the strategy. For each of the types of change, Level 2 considers the circumstances in which change is more likely to occur. The level of change in demand can be determined by knowledge of the change in the policy instrument in question and of the relevant elasticity of demand. Demand elasticities are generally calculated by estimating the proportionate change in demand for a good or service resulting from a one percent change in a measure of the supply of that good or service. Demand can be measured in trips or in trip-km for a given mode in a given circumstance. Supply can be defined in a number of different ways, including price, travel time, frequency or overall ("generalised") travel cost and it is important, in interpreting elasticities, to know which definition is being used. In particular, price might relate to "generalised cost", whereby all monetary and time-related costs to the user are bundled together, assigning a value to the time elements, or it might be defined in relation to one particular component of cost, eg fuel price or parking cost. Elasticities can also be measured for demand for the mode being affected (for example bus trips in response to changes in bus fares) or for demand for a competing mode (for example car trips in response to bus fares). The latter is referred to as a cross-elasticity. Changes in supply
For most policy instruments, the ways in which they affect supply are self-evident, but the scale of effect is not always clear. In Level 2, information is given for each policy instrument on the nature and level of the changes which are likely to arise. Interaction of demand and supply The way in which a policy instrument affects demand and supply curves will vary, as illustrated in the figures below, which represent five different types of change in the demand and supply for car use. In the first figure, the capacity of the road system has been increased, for example through traffic management; the supply curve has changed, but the demand curve, at least in the short term, has not, since the same number of users would wish to travel at a given cost. As a result, the number of users has increased, and the average cost of use has fallen. In the second figure, the capacity has been reduced, perhaps through a road closure; again the supply curve has changed, but the demand curve has not; the number of users has fallen, and the average cost increased. In the third figure, the demand for car use has fallen, perhaps through a reduction in public transport fares or a successful awareness campaign; the demand curve has changed, but the supply curve has not, since the costs of use at a given flow remain the same. As a result, the number travelling has fallen, as has the average cost of travel. In the fourth figure, the demand for car use has risen, perhaps through a deterioration in public transport services or an improvement in driver information. Again, the demand curve has changed but the supply curve has not; the number of car users has increased, as has the average cost of travel (though in this case, improved information may have reduced the perceived cost of use). In the fifth figure one of the many possible combinations of the above effects is shown. In this case, demand for car use has fallen, as has the capacity for car use. This could result, for example, from reallocation of road space to light rail. As a result both the demand and supply curves have changed. The number of car users has fallen, but the effect on average cost will depend on the relative changes in the demand and supply curves. Changes in costs The principal types of cost change are:
There are some policy instruments, including bus priorities, light rail provision and, more recently, Intelligent Transport Systems, for which demonstration projects have been implemented and documented. These are the best sources, since they usually indicate the performance of an instrument in a range of situations. There are others where individual studies have been conducted and reported in the professional literature. Some of these are of doubtful value because they have not been subject to a professional audit and may, in the extreme, have been designed to justify a scheme which was in practice less successful. There are, no doubt, far more which have been assessed, but where those carrying out the assessment have not seen fit to publish their results. In addition to the limited before and after studies, some evidence is available from desk studies which have used computer models to predict the impact of a policy instrument. This is, for example, still the main source of information on road pricing and comprehensive parking controls. These are potentially valuable but, of course, critically dependent on the quality of the model used. There have been a few attempts in the recent past to draw together this information; in some cases for a group of policy instruments (Webster et al 1980; ERTICO, 1998; Westerman, 1999); in others for the full range of policy measures (IHT, 1996; May and Still, 2000). What follows is based on the last of these. One of the most interesting attempts is the first web-based version: the "Transport Demand Management Encyclopedia," which was launched in 2000 (www.vtpi.org/tdm). One of the greatest problems in developing an information source of this
kind is to know whether results can be transferred from one location to
another. If a measure performs well in one city but not in another, is
it because it has been implemented more effectively in the first? Or are
the institutional arrangements different? Or is it because the cities
are subtly different in their topography, density or demography? Or are
there differences in culture which affect the willingness of individuals
to obey regulations or to switch modes? All of these factors make it very
difficult to transfer results from one city to another, even in the same
country, let alone between continents or cultures. 1. a description of the policy instrument and the way in which it operates,
with more detail provided for those which are less well known of more
complex; The tables which appear throughout Level Two are experimental. We would
very much welcome feedback on the usefulness of their content and design. European cities were asked for their assessment of the importance of
10 policy measures from these lists, chosen to reflect the range of types
of instrument. The results are shown in the figure below. Over 80% identified
bus priorities and bus and rail frequencies as important or very important,
and for most of the remainder at least 60% did. However, only 30% considered
road pricing important, and only 20% flexible working hours. Smaller cities
placed less emphasis on awareness campaigns, rail provision, bus priorities
and real time information than did medium and larger cities. Medium cities
placed greater emphasis on parking charges but less on road pricing. Larger
cities were less concerned with development patterns and with fares. In
addition, the survey cities identified a number of other policy measures
which they believed to be important, including park and ride, supplementary
housing construction, mobility management and pedestrianisation. Types of integration For all of these reasons, a package of measures is likely to be more effective than selecting any one measure on its own. A set of measures is likely to tackle more problems; one measure can offset the disadvantages of another or avoid the transfer of problems to another area; a second measure can reinforce the impact of the first, for example, inducing a change of mode and generating greater benefits. In these ways, synergy can be achieved between measures; that is, the overall benefits are greater than the sum of the parts. The identification of measures which might achieve such synergy is at the core of successful transport planning. There is currently considerable discussion of the principles of integration.
However, much of this focuses on integration specifically within public
transport. There is, in practice, a third and more strategic form of integration
which is directly relevant to strategy formulation: the integration of
policy measures to achieve greater performance from the overall strategy.
Such integration can occur in four broad ways:- integration between authorities
within a conurbation; integration between measures involving different
modes; integration between measures involving infrastructure provision,
management, information and pricing; and integration between transport
measures and land use planning measures. Integration at the strategic level can potentially achieve benefits in several ways. The first involves measures which complement one another in their impact on users. Obvious examples are the provision of park and ride to increase rail or bus patronage; the use of traffic calming to reinforce the benefits of building a bypass; the provision of public transport, or a fares reduction, to intensify the impact of traffic restraint; and the encouragement of new developments in conjunction with rail investment. The second involves measures which make other elements of the strategy financially feasible. Parking charges, a fares increase or road pricing revenue may all be seen as ways of providing finance for new infrastructure. The third concerns public acceptability, and the need to package measures which are less palatable on their own with ones which demonstrate a clear benefit to those affected. Once again an example is to be found in road pricing, which attitudinal research demonstrates is likely to be much more acceptable if the revenue is used to invest in public transport. The diagram below shows a selection of those measures described in previous sections, those which are particularly likely to complement one another in one of these ways. This diagram is intended to be used as a broad design guide only, not as a definitive assessment of instrument capability (IHT, 1996). There are important messages here, not just for the development of an
integrated strategy, but for the sequence in which measures are to be
implemented. Clearly those which need to be implemented to facilitate
others are required first. It will also be essential at least to be committed
to those measures which generate income before investing in those measures
which depend on that revenue for finance. Similar considerations arise
with measures which influence public acceptability: commitments are needed
to publicly attractive measures before embarking on those which on their
own are less attractive. Here, however, there is the continuing risk that
the less attractive measures will still not be implemented, for fear of
public criticism. It is preferable if both positive and negative measures
are implemented together. Use the blue arrows to select a measure.
|