|
A first principles assessment
Why introduce Parking Standards?
Demand impacts
Short and long run demand responses
Supply impacts
Maximum Parking Standards
Financing requirements
Expected impact on key policy objectives
Expected impact on problems
Expected winners and losers
Barriers to implementation
Why introduce Parking Standards?
Parking standards are set by local authorities to control the amount
of new PNR parking in their jurisdiction. There are a number of approaches
to setting parking standards, but they generally seek to either meet all
actual (and sometimes anticipated) demand for PNR parking or manage travel
demand through PNR parking availability. Additionally, parking spaces
take up land, so reducing parking capacity may reduce land take.
Demand impacts
In the UK, there is evidence to suggest that parking standards are set
mainly to meet expected demand, and that this has been overestimated in
most cases. This is despite national and regional planning guidance, such
as PPG13 (http://www.planning.odpm.gov.uk/ppg/ppg13/),
which indicates that parking standards should be set to encourage a reduction
in car traffic (DETR, 1998). Instead, the excess provision has encouraged
an increase in car travel. Excess provision is often attributed to fear
of negative consequences of competition between developments within an
area or between regions, when one has more generous standards than the
other. Responses and Situations, and Short and Long Run Demand Responses
are both completed on the basis of what should happen if the planning
guidelines were followed more closely.
Response |
Reduction in road traffic
|
Expected in situations |
|
|
Some drivers may leave home earlier to
get a parking space where they are allocated on a first come, first
served basis, but this will cause peak spreading, not a reduction
on vehicle kilometres. |
|
|
|
|
|
The introduction of a new development
will cause changes in destination, and/or a switch to public parking.
Restrictive parking standards may cause further shifts in search
of destinations with more parking, or shifts in location of development. |
|
|
Restrictive standards may cause drivers
to suppress non-essential trips or utilise alternatives to travel. |
|
|
Restrictive standards may cause modal
shift where alternatives are available. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
= Weakest
possible positive contribution, |
|
= strongest
possible positive contribution |
|
= Weakest
possible negative contribution |
|
= strongest
possible negative contribution |
|
=
No contribution |
Short and long run demand responses
Response |
- |
1st year |
2-4 years |
5 years |
10+ years |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Change job location |
|
|
|
|
- |
Shop elsewhere |
|
|
|
|
|
Compress working week* |
|
|
|
|
- |
Trip chain |
|
|
|
|
- |
Work from home |
|
|
|
|
- |
Shop from home |
|
|
|
|
|
Ride share |
|
|
|
|
- |
Public transport |
|
|
|
|
- |
Walk/cycle |
|
|
|
|
|
- |
|
|
|
|
|
- |
|
|
|
|
|
= Weakest
possible positive contribution, |
|
= strongest
possible positive contribution |
|
= Weakest
possible negative contribution |
|
= strongest
possible negative contribution |
|
=
No contribution |
*Where restrictive maximum standards mean that supply of parking does
not meet demand at a place of employment, employees may respond by compressing
their working week, to reduce the hassle of parking. This may be especially
so where near by public parking (both on and off street) is also scarce,
and/or expensive.
Supply impacts
Parking standards primarily affect the supply of new PNR parking. Current
planning guidance seeks to limit supply to a maximum level in new developments.
This category of parking is primarily office and retail, but also includes
hospitals, schools and other public services. Supply of public parking
can be influenced where the commuted payments from developers approach
is adopted. There is no precedent for supplying road space in this way,
but commuted payments have been used for public transport.
The maximum parking standards suggested by PPG13 are set out in Maximum
Parking Standards.
Maximum Parking Standards
Use |
National Maximum Parking Standard
1 space per square metre (m2) of gross floor space unless otherwise
stated |
Threshold from and Above Which Standard Applies
(gross floor space) |
Food retail |
1 space per 14m2 |
1000m2 |
Non food retail |
1 space per 20m2 |
1000m2 |
Cinemas and conference facilities |
1 space per 5 seats |
1000m2 |
D2 (other than cinemas, conference facilities
and stadia) |
1 space per 22m2 |
1000m2 |
B1 including offices |
1 space per 30m2 |
2500m2 |
Higher and further education |
1 space per 2 staff
+ 1 space per 15 students
(see note 1) |
2500m2 |
Stadia |
1 space per 15 seats
(see note 2) |
1500 seats |
Notes:
-
The standard for students relates to the total
number of students attending an educational establishment, rather
than full-time equivalent figures.
-
For stadia, sufficient coach parking should be
provided to the satisfaction of the local authority and treated separately
from car parking. Coach parking should be designed and managed so
that it will not be used for car parking.
-
Parking for disabled people should be additional
to the maximum parking standards. Development proposals should provide
adequate parking for disabled motorists, in terms of numbers and design
(see Traffic Advice Leaflet 5/95, Parking for Disabled People).
-
For mixed use development, the gross floorspace
given over to each use should be used to calculate the overall total
maximum parking figure. For land uses not covered in these standards,
the most stringent regional or local standards should apply.
Source: PPG13, 2001.
A detailed example of how these standards are applied in practice (including
reductions in the maximum permissible PNR provision) is provided by
Hampshire County Council in the UK, at http://www.hants.gov.uk/carparking/index.html
Financing requirements
Parking standards themselves do not require any financial commitments
on the part of the local authority. However, where commuted payments
are required, the authority may make some contribution to the public
parking or public transport funded in this way. Local authorities are
able to specify the value of commuted payments, which can vary annually
according to the retail price index. The following values are set by
the City of York Council in the UK.
Cars |
Business (B1) |
£3000 per space |
|
Retail (A1, A2, A3) |
£5000 per space |
Cycles |
|
£100 per space for uncovered spaces |
|
|
£500 per space for covered spaces |
“All commuted sums payable after 31 March 1996 will vary according
to the Retail Price Index and will contribute towards providing appropriate
additional transport facilities for the particular location concerned”
(http://www.york.gov.uk/environment/york/localplan/appe/).
NB: B1, A1, A2 and A3 are categories of land use defined in the UK.
Expected impact on key policy objectives
Assessments of impacts on key policy objectives are made on the basis
of parking standards that follow planning guidance to restrict supply
of PNR parking.
Objective |
Scale of contribution |
Comment |
|
|
Reductions in congestion will improve
efficiency. |
|
|
Reductions in car traffic will contribute
positively towards liveable streets, but the greatest impacts
may not be in residential areas. |
|
|
Reductions in car traffic will reduce
atmospheric and noise pollution, whilst reductions in PNR parking
supply may reduce land take. |
|
|
Those who continue to driver and non-car
users will benefit from reductions in congestion (and possibly
improved services if there is sufficient modal shift to warrant
changes). However, those who would previously have had the perk
of private parking get less net benefit. |
|
|
Reductions in car use will help to
reduce road accidents. |
|
/ |
Improvements in efficiency will contribute
positively towards economic growth. However, it is argued that
restrictions will reduce development, and that this is a serious
negative impact. |
|
|
No financial commitments are required. |
|
= Weakest
possible positive contribution, |
|
= strongest
possible positive contribution |
|
= Weakest
possible negative contribution |
|
= strongest
possible negative contribution |
|
=
No contribution |
Expected impact on problems
Assessments of impacts in terms of alleviation of key problems are
made on the basis of parking standards that follow planning guidance
to restrict supply of PNR parking.
Contribution to alleviation of key problems |
Problem |
Scale of contribution |
Comment |
Congestion-related delay |
|
Where alternatives to car use making
modal shift feasible. Where this is not the case, congestion will
either be severe as a result of traffic searching for a parking
space, or congestion will shift to an alternative destination. |
Congestion-related unreliability |
|
Where alternatives to car use making
modal shift feasible. Where this is not the case, congestion will
either be severe as a result of traffic searching for a parking
space, or congestion will shift to an alternative destination. |
Community severance |
|
Where corridors dissect local neighbourhoods
amenity areas. |
Visual intrusion |
|
Large car parks at ground level or
multi-storey can have significant negative visual impacts, especially
in areas where land use development is not dense, or landscaping
is poor. Thus, restricting new PNR can reduce visual intrusion. |
Lack of amenity |
- |
|
Global warming |
|
Reductions in traffic levels and congestion
will reduce pollution. |
Local air pollution |
|
Reductions in traffic levels and congestion
will reduce pollution. |
Noise |
|
Reductions in traffic levels and congestion
will reduce pollution. |
Reduction of green space |
|
Limiting parking provision will reduce
land take. |
Damage to environmentally sensitive sites |
|
Limiting parking provision will reduce
land take and traffic impact on environmentally sensitive sites. |
Poor accessibility for those without a car and
those with mobility impairments |
|
Users of alternative modes will benefit
from reductions in congestion. |
Disproportionate disadvantaging of particular
social or geographic groups |
|
Those in areas with poor alternatives
to the car. |
Number, severity and risk of accidents |
|
Reduced traffic levels will reduce
the accident risk. |
Suppression of the potential for economic activity
in the area |
|
Reduced congestion will make the area
more attractive, although restrictive parking standards may make
an area unattractive if standards in neighbouring areas allow
more parking. |
|
= Weakest
possible positive contribution, |
|
= strongest
possible positive contribution |
|
= Weakest
possible negative contribution |
|
= strongest
possible negative contribution |
|
=
No contribution |
Expected winners and losers
Group |
Winners / losers |
Comment |
Large scale freight and commercial traffic |
|
Such traffic spends only a small proportion
of its time in urban conditions, but where it does, it will benefit
from reduced congestion. |
Small businesses |
|
These will benefit from the efficiency
gains brought about by reduced congestion. |
High income car-users |
|
These will benefit from the efficiency
gains brought about by reduced congestion. |
People with a low income |
/ |
Those unable to afford a car and using
public transport instead will benefit from reduced congestion,
as will low income car users who continue to travel by car. Those
forced to leave their car at home and pay for public transport,
or pay for use of a public parking space will suffer financial
disbenefits. |
People with poor access to public transport |
|
Where parking becomes difficult there
will be a disbenefit, especially if limited PNR parking forces
drivers to pay for use of public space. |
All existing public transport users |
|
Public transport will benefits from
reduced congestion and potentially improved services where demand
increases sufficiently to warrant this. |
People living adjacent to the area targeted |
|
There may be substantial increases
in parking around the edge of a new development with restricted
PNR. |
People making high value, important journeys
|
|
These people will benefit from reduced
congestion. |
The average car user |
|
The average car user will benefit from
reduced congestion. |
|
=
weakest possible benefit, |
|
=
strongest benefit |
|
= weakest
possible disbenefet, |
|
= strongest
possible disbenefit |
|
= neither
wins nor loses |
Barriers to implementation
Barrier |
Scale |
Comment |
Legal |
/ |
There are relatively few legal barriers
to controlling new PNR parking, but control existing space is
virtually impossible. |
Finance |
|
No commitments are required. |
Political |
|
Where restrictive standards will make
neighbouring areas more attractive. |
Feasibility |
|
Once standards are agreed they are
relatively easy to apply through the planning system. |
|
=
minimal barrier, |
|
=
most significant barrier |
|