|
First
principles assessment
Why use land use planning to encourage less
personal motorised travel?
Demand impacts
Short and long term demand responses
Level of response
Supply impacts
Financing requirements
Expected impacts on key policy objectives
Contribution to the achievement of objectives
Expected impact on problem alleviation
Expected winners and losers
Barriers to implementation
Why use land use planning to encourage less personal
motorised travel?
The importance of the interactions between spatial (land use) planning
and management, and the design, operation and use of transport systems,
is fully recognised. Important aspects of this are (Cost 332):
- the spatial organisation engendered by the evolution of the production
process increases personal mobility requirements (and those for goods
movements),
- low density development, particularly in the suburbs, has encouraged
the growth of travel and of multi-car households;
- the growing polarisation of commercial structures has also led to
an increase in personal travel, particularly by car.
The reversal or reduction of these land use development trends will tend
to reduce the need to travel in general and travel by car in particular.
Land use changes, however, take quite a long time, so this is not a short-term
policy instrument.
The trends listed above may be illustrated by the cases shown in the
following table:
Relationship between transport and location of
property development |
Location/land use |
Effect |
Source |
Out-of-town business parks, UK |
93% use car to travel to work |
RCEP, 1994 |
Gateshead MetroCentre, UK |
80% travel by car compared to 27% to the city centre |
TEST, 1989 |
Copenhagen insurance company moving from centre (near station)
to suburbs |
Car commuting up from 26% to 54% |
ECMT and OECD, 1995 |
Supermarket on free-standing outer London site |
95% by car compared to 33% for inner London supermarket |
RCEP, 1994 |
Source: Lucas, Marsh and Jones, p.16.
The table below indicates how various land use design features are estimated
to reduce per capita vehicle trip generation compared with conventional
development that lacks these features (Online TDM Encyclopaedia).
Travel Impacts of Land Use Design Features (Dagang, 1995)
Design Feature |
Reduced Vehicle Travel |
Residential development around public transport nodes |
10% |
Commercial development around public transport nodes |
15% |
Residential development along public transport corridor. |
5% |
Commercial development along public transport corridor. |
7% |
Residential mixed-use development around public transport nodes |
15% |
Commercial mixed-use development around public transport nodes |
20% |
Residential mixed-use development along public transport corridors. |
7% |
Commercial mixed-use development along public transport corridors. |
10% |
Residential mixed-use development. |
5% |
Commercial mixed-use development. |
7% |
Source: Online TDM
Encyclopaedia
Demand impacts
Increasing development densities and altering
the development mix have an effect on demand in two ways:
- Reducing the need for motorised travel (especially private motorised
travel) by ensuring origins and destinations are closer together (the
topic of this section);
- Encouraging public transport use by improving conditions to enable
public transport to operate more efficiently (dealt with separately
under 'Encouraging Public Transport Use Through
Land Use Planning' ;
It is the demand impact of the first of these which is the subject of
the following table and the remainder of this section.
Responses and situations |
Response |
Reduction in road traffic
|
Expected in situations |
|
|
Change of departure time is not an effect of this instrument |
|
|
Change of route is not an effect of this instrument |
|
|
Higher densities and more mixed land uses bring more destinations
of a particular type within easier reach |
|
|
Higher densities and more mixed land uses bring more destinations
of a particular type within easier reach |
|
|
Change of mode to public transport may occur where the change
in land use makes the operation of public transport more viable,
thus a better service |
|
|
Where a sufficient range of destinations is available within
a short distance, a car may become less necessary and so some may
sell it |
|
|
Encouraging moving house is not an objective of this instrument,
nor is it a feasible outcome |
|
=
Weakest possible response, |
|
=
strongest possible positive response |
|
= Weakest
possible negative response, |
|
= strongest
possible negative response |
|
= No response
|
Short and long term demand responses
Of all the instruments contained in these pages, land use instruments
are perhaps the ones which, potentially at least, can have the greatest
impact on reducing the amount of motorised travel. However, they are also
the ones which take the longest to implement and thus to bear fruit. The
greatest opportunities for change are in the circumstances of entirely
new development, when land use densities and mixes may be specified in
advance. Even in these conditions however, results will take years to
materialise
Response |
- |
1st year |
2-4 years |
5 years |
10+ years |
Change departure time |
- |
|
|
|
|
Change route |
- |
|
|
|
|
Change destination |
Change job location |
|
|
|
|
- |
Shop elsewhere |
|
|
|
|
Reduce number of journeys |
Compress working week |
|
|
|
|
- |
Trip chain |
|
|
|
|
- |
Work from home |
|
|
|
|
- |
Shop from home |
|
|
|
|
Change mode |
Ride share |
|
|
|
|
- |
Public transport |
|
|
|
|
- |
Walk/cycle |
|
|
|
|
Sell car |
- |
|
|
|
|
Change home location |
- |
|
|
|
|
|
=
Weakest possible response, |
|
=
strongest possible positive response |
|
= Weakest
possible negative response, |
|
= strongest
possible negative response |
|
= No response
|
Level of response
The amount of reduction in the amount of motorised travel in response
to land use instruments, will depend on:
- the scale of the land use changes;
- the design and type of the changes, in terms of density and mix;
- the speed with which the changes are effected.
In all cases, there will be no response in the short term and very little
in the medium term, as indicated in the table above.
One study of travel patterns in a North American suburb found the elasticity
of transit (public transport) mode split with respect to land use density
to be +0.10 to +0.51, depending on type of land use. This means that each
1.0% increase in density increases public transport use by 0.1-0.51% (Cervero
(2002) in Online TDM
Encyclopaedia).
Ewing and Cervero (2002) calculate the elasticity of per capita vehicle
trips and vehicle travel with respect to various land use factors, as
summarized in the table below. For example, this indicates that doubling
neighbourhood density reduces per capita car travel by 5%. Similarly,
doubling land use mix or improving land use design to support alternative
modes also reduces per capita car travel by 5%. Although these factors
may be small, they are cumulative. (Online
TDM Encyclopaedia)
Typical Elasticities of Travel With Respect to the Built Environment (Ewing
and Cervero, 2002) in Online
TDM Encyclopaedia))
Factor |
Description |
Trips |
VMT |
Local Density |
Residents and employees divided by land area. |
-0.05 |
-0.05 |
Local Diversity (Mix) |
Jobs/residential population |
-0.03 |
-0.05 |
Local Design |
Sidewalk completeness/route directness and street network density. |
-0.05 |
-0.03 |
Regional Accessibility |
Distance to other activity centres in the region. |
-- |
-0.20 |
This table shows the elasticity values of Vehicle Trips and Vehicle Miles
Travelled (VMT) with respect to various land use factors.
This suggests that neighbourhood design factors (density, mix and design)
can reduce per capita vehicle travel on the order of 10-20%, while regional
accessibility factors (i.e., where a neighbourhood is located with respect
to the urban centre) can reduce car travel by 20-40%. (Online
TDM Encyclopaedia)
Supply impacts
The supply implications are as follows:
- There will not be an increase in the supply of road space from land
use instruments per se, though there might be additional local requirements,
e.g. for access to new development, including by bus;
- If the land use policies are implemented on a regional scale, there
could be a nett reduction in the need for road space (compared with
doing nothing) in line with the decrease in the amount of travel;
- Higher density development could improve conditions for public transport
and thus encourage greater public transport supply; (dealt with separately
under 'Encouraging Public Transport Use Through
Land Use Planning';
- Reduction in private motorised travel could encourage an increase
in the supply of cycle and pedestrian facilities;
- Any reduction in car ownership would reduce the need for residential
parking supply;
- Any reduction in 'motorised destinations' would reduce the need for
non-residential parking supply.
Financing requirements
Though the costs of new development are considerable and land use solutions
are, at their most extreme, the most expensive of the policy instruments
contained in these pages, the cost usually falls in the main on the private
sector (through investors, developers and occupiers). However, local authorities
may have to bear some additional indirect costs (provision of extra traffic
control, parking, public transport interchanges, etc).
Though it is difficult to cost this instrument, the range of possibilities
being so large, some comments on cost can nevertheless be made.
Firstly, regarding individual developments, it has been estimated (Lucas,
Marsh and Jones, p.19) that if development conforms to a standard to reflect
sustainable development, construction costs will rise typically between
5 per cent and 20 per cent. Unfortunately the proportion of this extra
cost related solely to attaining sustainable transport is not known but
clearly there would be some additional cost if land use development had
to conform to sustainable transport criteria.
There are ways of financing the extra costs of achieving a transport-friendly
development policy, particularly where the extra cost would normally fall
on the local authority. These ways include:
- Commuted payments
- Developer contributions
If development costs are looked at region-wide, an alternative picture
on costs may occur, as illustrated in the following table (costs in Canadian
dollars) (Online TDM Encyclopaedia)
Estimated 25 Year Public Costs for Three Development Options
(Blais, 1995)
|
Spread |
Nodal |
Central |
Residents per Ha |
66 |
98 |
152 |
Capital Costs (billion Canadian $ 1995) |
54.8 |
45.1 |
39.1 |
Op & Maint Costs (billion C$ 1995) |
14.3 |
11.8 |
10.1 |
Total Costs |
69.1 |
56.9 |
49.2 |
Percent Savings over status quo option |
0 |
17% |
29% |
This table shows substantial public savings for higher density land use
patterns associated with transport-friendly development.
Finally, one interesting issue regarding financing is the possibility
of higher land and property values arising from improved accessibility,
and how the local authority can get its hands on a slice of it.
Expected impacts on key policy objectives
Increasing land uses densities and modifying development mix encourage
people to change their travel behaviour and in particular to travel less
by car, through the mechanisms explained earlier. The resulting reduction
in car travel can have significant effects on the various Konsult objectives
as shown in the table below. Once again, these impacts are approximate
as the scale of the effects depends largely on the scale of land use changes.
Objective |
Scale of
contribution |
Comment |
|
|
By reducing
motor traffic |
|
|
By reducing
motor traffic |
|
|
By reducing
motor traffic |
|
|
Through increased accessibility |
|
|
By reducing
motor traffic |
|
|
More attractive
location |
|
? |
Uncertain effect |
|
= Weakest
possible positive contribution, |
|
= strongest
possible positive contribution |
|
= Weakest
possible negative contribution |
|
= strongest
possible negative contribution |
|
=
No contribution |
Expected impact on problem alleviation
The expected impacts of changes in land use density and mix on problem
alleviation are summarised in the following table.
Contribution to the alleviation of
key problems |
Problem |
Scale of contribution |
Comment |
Congestion-related delay |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general |
Congestion-related unreliability |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general |
Community severance |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general |
Visual intrusion |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general and the improved visual
effect of ‘better’ development |
Lack of amenity |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general and the improved amenity
effect of ‘better’ development |
CO2 emissions |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general and reducing congestion |
Local air pollution |
|
By reducing motor traffic and congestion in local centres.
Reduction in cold starts from fewer car trips. |
Noise |
|
By reducing motor traffic and congestion in local centers |
Reduction of green space |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general and the opportunity to
incorporate green space in new development |
Damage to environmentally-sensitive areas |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general |
Poor accessibility for those without a car and those with
mobility impairments |
|
By encouraging a situation for more viable public transport
and by easier movement in newly-designed centres |
Disproportionate disadvantaging of particular social or geographical
groups |
|
By encouraging a situation for more viable public transport,
social and geographical groups are made more ‘accessibility equal’ |
Number, severity and risk of accidents |
|
By reducing motor traffic in general and in local centres
(pedestrian safety) in particular |
Suppression of the potential for economic activity in the
area |
|
Insofar as land use planning maintains accessibility, the
area should become more attractive as a location due to better amenity.
If land use planning increases accessibility, this effect should
be amplified. |
|
= Weakest
possible positive contribution, |
|
= strongest
possible positive contribution |
|
= Weakest
possible negative contribution |
|
= strongest
possible negative contribution |
|
=
No contribution |
Expected winners and losers
It is difficult to see how there can be any losers if policies of land
use density and mix are wisely applied. This is because there should be
a wider range of destinations within a given distance and public transport
operations are made easier. There is no discouragement per se to any motorised
mode: the reduction in traffic by reducing the need to travel will in
fact benefit all motorised modes.
Group |
Winners / losers |
Comment |
Large scale freight and commercial
traffic |
|
Reduced
congestion |
Small businesses |
|
Reduced
congestion, better public transport access for employees and customers |
High income car-users |
|
Reduced
congestion |
People with a low income |
|
Public
transport access will improve |
People with poor access to public
transport |
|
Public
transport access will improve |
All existing public transport
users |
|
Public
transport access will improve |
People living adjacent to the
area targeted |
|
They may benefit from reduced
congestion and improved or increased public transport supply. |
People making high value, important
journeys |
|
Bus and
car access improved |
The average car user |
|
Where they are able to travel
more efficiently, saving time and money. Plus getting more exercise
through modal shift to walking and cycling, and experiencing the community
benefits, which accrue from these modes. |
|
=
weakest possible benefit, |
|
=
strongest benefit |
|
= weakest
possible disbenefet, |
|
= strongest
possible disbenefit |
|
= neither
wins nor loses |
Barriers to implementation
There are potentially severe barriers to implementation, particularly
financial and related to feasibility. Legal barriers may also be serious
in cases where the current planning legislation would need amendment for
this instrument to be implemented.
Barriers to implementation |
Barrier |
Scale |
Comment |
Legal |
|
If legislation not in place |
Financial |
|
Unless developers can be persuaded to pay in some way for
‘sustainability upgrade’ of their developments |
Political |
|
Time needed to effect changes may make the instrument politically
unattractive |
Feasibility |
|
Not infeasible per se but amount of time needed may
reduce feasibility |
|
=
minimal barrier, |
|
=
most significant barrier |
|